Forwards and Futures
Among all derivatives, forwards and futures are the simplest.
They are linear contracts whose payoffs vary one-for-one with the underlying price.
Understanding their pricing through the lens of no-arbitrage provides the mathematical foundation for all derivative valuation.
1. What Are Forwards and Futures?
Forward Contract
A forward is a private OTC agreement to exchange an asset at a fixed price $K$ on a future date $T$.
- Long forward: commits to buy at $K$.
- Short forward: commits to sell at $K$.
At maturity, the long receives:
\[\Pi_T = S_T - K.\]Futures Contract
A futures contract is the exchange-traded equivalent:
- standardized contract size and expiry,
- daily mark-to-market settlement through a clearinghouse,
- margin requirements that limit credit exposure.
2. The No-Arbitrage Pricing Principle
Pricing of forwards and futures rests on the idea that identical future payoffs must cost the same today.
Assume:
- Current spot price of the asset: $S_0$
- Continuous risk-free rate: $r$
- Continuous yield on the asset (dividend, foreign interest, or convenience yield): $q$
- Time to maturity: $T$
We construct replicating portfolios to enforce price consistency.
2.1 Cash-and-Carry Arbitrage
Imagine the forward is over-priced ($F_0 > S_0 e^{(r - q)T}$).
We can lock in risk-free profit via a cash-and-carry strategy:
- Borrow $S_0$ cash at rate $r$.
- Buy one unit of the underlying asset at $S_0$.
- Short one forward at price $F_0$ (agree to sell later).
At maturity $T$:
- Deliver the asset into the forward and receive $F_0$.
- Repay the loan $S_0 e^{rT}$.
- Receive any income (dividends or yield) of $S_0(e^{qT}-1)$.
The total terminal payoff:
\[\text{Profit} = F_0 - S_0 e^{(r - q)T}.\]If $F_0$ is indeed higher than $S_0 e^{(r - q)T}$, this profit is positive and arbitrage exists.
Competition pushes $F_0$ down until equality holds.
2.2 Reverse Cash-and-Carry Arbitrage
Conversely, if the forward is under-priced ($F_0 < S_0 e^{(r - q)T}$):
- Short sell one unit of the underlying at $S_0$.
- Invest the proceeds at rate $r$.
- Go long one forward at $F_0$ (agree to buy later).
At $T$:
- Buy back the asset via the forward for $F_0$.
- Collect the matured investment $S_0 e^{rT}$.
- Pay any carry cost or yield $S_0(e^{qT}-1)$.
The payoff is:
\[\text{Profit} = S_0 e^{(r - q)T} - F_0.\]If positive, arbitrageurs buy forwards and short spot, driving prices back to parity.
2.3 Equilibrium Relation
In equilibrium (no free lunch), both strategies yield zero profit:
\[F_0 = S_0 e^{(r - q)T}.\]This is the cost-of-carry model — the cornerstone of forward and futures pricing.
2.4 Example: Equity Forward on a Dividend-Paying Stock
Suppose:
- Current stock price $S_0 = 100$
- Annual risk-free rate $r = 5\%$
- Continuous dividend yield $q = 2\%$
- Maturity $T = 0.5$ years
Then
\[F_0 = 100\, e^{(r - q)T} = 100\, e^{(0.05 - 0.02)\times0.5} = 101.51.\]Arbitrage Intuition
If a forward were quoted at $F_0 = 103$:
- You would short the forward, buy the stock, and borrow $100.
- In 6 months:
receive $103$, repay $100 e^{0.05\times0.5}=102.53$, receive dividends ≈ $1. - Net profit ≈ $1.47 risk-free → arbitrage.
2.5 Visualization
The diagram illustrates how arbitrage connects spot, carry, and forward value:
if the forward is too high → cash-and-carry (sell forward, buy spot);
too low → reverse cash-and-carry (buy forward, sell spot).
3. Futures Pricing and Convexity
For deterministic interest rates, futures and forwards have the same fair value.
However, with stochastic rates:
because futures are marked to market daily.
If $\text{corr}(r_t, S_t) > 0$, the long futures tends to outperform the forward — a positive convexity bias.
4. Market Usage
Sector | Purpose | Typical Instrument |
---|---|---|
Corporates | Hedge commodity or FX exposure | Oil futures, FX forwards |
Investors | Adjust equity exposure | Index futures |
Banks | Construct forward rate curves | FRA, Eurodollar futures |
Hedge funds | Relative-value arbitrage | Calendar spreads |
These instruments underpin price discovery across asset classes.
5. Summary
- No-arbitrage ensures $F_0 = S_0 e^{(r - q)T}$.
- Cash-and-carry and reverse carry strategies enforce this relation.
- Forwards and futures bridge present and future market prices.
- Small deviations signal funding or collateral effects rather than arbitrage.
Next up: Options: Basics and Put–Call Parity
Comments